I’ve never been a big believer in the wisdom of voters. Indeed, I’ve devoted much of my academic career to writing about the dangers of widespread political ignorance, going all the way back to my first academic article. It was published in 1998, at a time when most experts tended to be relatively optimistic about voter competence. Since then, I published a book on the subjectâDemocracy and Political Ignorance â and many other articles exploring various dimensions of the problem, its implications for legal and political theory, and possible solutions.
In these works, I explained how most voters often don’t know even basic facts about the political system and government policy, and those that know more (the “political fans”), often tend to evaluate political information in a highly biased way. I also argued that information shortcuts and “miracles of aggregation” largely fail to offset ignorance and bias, and sometimes even make things worse. Moreover, this sad state of affairs is not the result of stupidity or lack of information, but of generally rational behavior on the part of most voters: a combination of “rational ignorance” (lack of incentive to seek out political information) and “rational irrationality” (lack of incentive to engage in unbiased evaluation).
Since the rise of Trump and similar politicians in other countries, academics and political commentators have become more aware of the dangers of public ignorance. I wish I could say my own take on the subject has been vindicated. But, in one crucial respect, the Trump era has shown I wasn’t pessimistic enough.
Though I have long argued that voter ignorance and bias are serious dangers, and that information shortcuts are overrated, I also asserted that shortcuts actually work well in one important way: democratic electorates will punish politicians who cause great harm in clear and obvious ways. For example, I cited economist Amartya Sen’s famous finding that mass famines never or almost never occur under democracies, while they are all too common under dictatorship. Even ignorant and biased voters will notice a famine is going on, blame incumbent politicians for it, and punish them at the ballot box. Knowing this, democratic political leaders have strong incentives to avoid famines and other obvious disasters. And they generally do just that, at least when they have the necessary knowledge and resources (disasters can still happen if avoiding them is difficult).
“Retrospective voting”ârewarding and punishing incumbents for things that happen on their watchâoften works poorly in less extreme and less clear-cut cases. As explained in Chapter 4 of my book, voters often reward or punish office-holders for things they didn’t cause (most notably short-term economic trends; but also things like droughts and even sports-team victories), while ignoring some that they are in fact responsible for. But retrospective voting is a great mechanism for punishing politicians for obvious large-scale awfulness, one that works very well.
Or so I thought, along with many other scholars. But Trump proved me at least partially wrong. I was too optimistic.
Trump’s effort to use force and fraud to overturn the 2020 election was exactly the sort of obvious and blatant awfulness that retrospective voting theory predicts the electorate should decisively repudiate. Peaceful transitions of power are fundamental to democracy, and Trump’s 2020 activities struck at the very heart of this norm. Had he succeeded, it would have severely damaged the basic structure of our liberal democratic institutions. Yet a large majority of GOP voters renominated Trump again this year. And he has roughly an even chance to win the general election this year. If he goes on to lose, it will probably be by a very narrow margin, not the kind of overwhelming repudiation that would vindicate the theory.
Some people who would otherwise vote GOP are punishing Trump for his 2020 behavior by voting for Harris, or at least abstaining. Mike Pence and former GOP Rep. Liz Cheney are not alone. Thanks in part to these defectors, Trump is doing worse than a Republican nominee untainted by 2020 probably would be. But the number of such voters is much smaller than optimistic versions of retrospective voting theory would predict.
Ignorance and bias are playing a huge role in Trump’s relative success. Polls consistently show that a third or more of Americansâincluding a large majority of Republicansâbelieve Trump’s lies about the 2020 election, despite the overwhelming evidence against them, including numerous court decisions rejecting Trumpian claims of voter fraud (including some written by conservative judges appointed by Trump himself). Ignorance and partisan bias are great enough that many millions of GOP base voters reject fairly obvious facts here. If you believe the 2020 election was “stolen” from Trump, then his reaction may well seem justified, or at least excusable.
But this isn’t the full story. If Trump only had the support of voters who actually believe his lies about the 2020 election, he could still have won the 2024 GOP nomination. But he would be losing the general election in a landslide of about 60-40 or even more. He remains competitive with Kamala Harris because there are many voters (probably around 10-15% or so of the electorate) who reject his take on 2020, but prioritize other issues, such as the economy or immigration.
Here, more conventional political ignorance is playing a role. Most polls that the economy is the highest priority for voters, including swing voters, and many are angry about the inflation and price increases that took place in 2021-23. Here, there is a fairly standard political ignorance story. Swing voters blame incumbent Democrats for the inflation and price increases, even though actually both parties supported the policies that caused them (primarily massive Covid-era spending).
Even more concerning is the fact that many voters believe that Trump will lower prices, despite the fact that his proposed policies of imposing high tariffs and restricting immigration would actually lead to price increases. This misunderstanding of the impact of policies is common among swing voters, who prioritize issues like price increases over Trump’s actions in 2020. This flawed retrospective voting prevents effective punishment of Trump’s dangerous actions and their threat to the constitutional system.
Similarly, misconceptions about immigration contribute to support for Trump’s restrictive policies. In reality, increased immigration is beneficial, and easing legal migration is the best solution to border disorder. The belief that immigration is an “invasion” and a major crisis is rooted in ignorance.
Some voters may downplay Trump’s attempt to overturn the election in 2020 by arguing that his efforts failed and the “guardrails” held. However, supporting a leader who tried to drive the country off a cliff is irrational and dangerous, as it sets a dangerous precedent and encourages further undemocratic behavior.
History shows that failing to retrospectively penalize terrible policies and candidates due to misinformation can have severe consequences. Ignorance and flawed retrospective voting in Europe led to the rise of the Nazis. In the US, ignorance during the Great Depression led to harmful policies that worsened the crisis.
While the current issues of price increases and border problems may not compare to past crises, they still reveal the limitations of retrospective voting. Democracy is still preferable to dictatorship, but the threshold for holding politicians accountable may be higher than previously believed. Voter ignorance and bias are pervasive across the political spectrum, as evidenced by the Trump situation. The outcome of the election will determine if voters are willing to hold Trump accountable for his actions.
However, if he emerges victorious, or only suffers a narrow defeat, then the heightened sense of pessimism is indeed justified.
There is no quick fix for political ignorance. In a recent article on “Top-Down and Bottom-Up Solutions to the Problem of Political Ignorance,” as well as in my book Democracy and Political Ignorance, I explore various possible options. I advocate for reducing the number of decisions made at the ballot box and increasing decisions made by “voting with your feet,” as this incentivizes individuals to seek out and utilize information more effectively. However, I acknowledge that implementing an effective solution will require time, and no single fix may be sufficient on its own. It may be necessary to employ a combination of strategies.
Nevertheless, recent events indicate that the issue of political ignorance may be even more severe than previously thought. This underscores the urgency of finding viable solutions.